What’s Wrong with Our UK Tax System ?
In short – it stifles incentive and enterprise, thus reducing UK productivity and wealth generation.....
Let me try to explain.
The Covid pandemic, Brexit, and more recently the worldwide ‘cost of living crisis’ have undoubtedly put a huge strain on many western economies since the start of the decade, and the UK is no exception.
The many billions gobbled up by pandemic costs and the furlough scheme in particular were but one example of the financial challenges we faced, and the debt incurred will still have to be paid for somehow.
Raising
taxes was a logical response during the first years of the pandemic in an
attempt to pay down some of our mounting debt. Maintenance of ultra-low interest rates
and effectively ‘printing money’ via quantitative easing was another means adopted
to try and soften the immediate economic blow in the late 2010s, but unfortunately had the effect of making the
economy appear more robust than it actually was....and building up our debt mountain alarmingly in the process.
These historically exceptional policies, which were in any case out of kilter with conventional capitalist economics, were never going to be a long term solution
to our economic ills, however, and could be likened to ‘sticking plaster’ to
prevent the financial ‘wounds’ the economy had sustained over the last 10 years from getting infected. By 2023 the sticking plaster was
definitely passed its best, and like all sticking plasters, needed to come off to give the old wound a chance to
heal. Maintaining the old policies for too long, as we did, has arguably already
proved to be injurious in stoking debt and helping drive inflation, and we needed a rapid re-think before the damage
progressed too far and the ‘wounds’ start to get re-infected.
Our main economic problem in the UK over the past 5 years or so has been lack of growth and chronic low productivity, coupled with a measure of worldwide post-pandemic over-expansion and consequent supply-demand mismatch. These are closely interconnected, and are the end-product of two decades of aberrant tax and financial policies, a worldwide financial crisis, and nearly a decade of consequent austerity - and of course, more recently, a new war in Europe.
We are also a
rapidly ageing society, and this major demographic change, along with our
historic attitudes to employing older workers, and, of course, Brexit have all created a major imbalance
in the working population and acute shortages of workers in some sectors. This,
in turn, has caused a chronic and seemingly perpetual series of crises, and
more recently an upward trend in industrial unrest, all of which threatens to bring
our normal daily life inexorably to a halt.
How has the tax system contributed to this, and how could we
change it to reverse the trend ?
Although Sunak, as chancellor, did make some early tax and benefit concessions in an attempt to alleviate the worst effects of the cost of living crisis, these were few and far between, and the trend since the start of the pandemic has been toward an ever-increasing total tax burden. Both personal and business finances have been badly affected by this.
The decision to freeze personal tax thresholds (widely dubbed a 'stealth' tax) was a particularly perverse and regressive one on Sunak's part and the present government have eagerly perpetuated it in an attempt to secure more tax revenue. Its principal effect has been to stifle any incentive middle-earners might otherwise have had to progress onwards and upwards, without actually helping those lower down the earnings scale.
Imposing a hefty increase in NI contributions in the October 2024, just as prices and operating costs started to rise again, was another major disincentive,
this time for both employees and employers, who quite reasonably reacted by cutting their
recruiting plans to save the extra employment costs, thereby worsening the
employment and productivity crisis. The large hike in the minimum wage put additional strain on business, and forthcoming adverse changes to employment legislation may well turn out to be the 'coup de grace' for some SMEs.
Why does freezing tax thresholds provide such a strong disincentive
to self-advancement ?
To explain this, I’ll provide a fictitious, but I think perfectly plausible, example.
Edward is a young middle-manager in his mid-30s based in the north of England, and is married
with two young children. He currently earns just under £50,000 p.a. His wife Mary
is still working part time, but with two young pre-school children she prefers to
keep her hours to a minimum, so her net financial contribution to the household budget is small. The burgeoning
cost of childcare isn’t helping things and she anticipates having to reduce her
hours further and perhaps even stop working altogether, to keep childcare costs down.
Edward has had an offer of a promotion to a regional manager post to fill a key position which recently fell vacant due to an unexpected early retirement. He feels encouraged by this offer, but is also a little daunted by it, since the new post carries a lot more responsibility and involves a move to a different (and more expensive) area of the country. His new salary would be ca £70,000 including use of a company car, but his hours would be longer and he would need to spend more hours away from home and his young family.
Should he take the promotion ?
Being a prudent soul, Edward takes a good look at the figures before making a decision, and finds that, quite apart from any detrimental effects on family life, he would actually end up significantly worse off, and with a much higher level of mortgage debt, if he took on the new job.
His main problem is tax – the extra £20,000 he earns will all be taxed at 40%, and by moving into the 40% tax bracket he loses another £500 allowance on any savings income he might receive. His family’s child benefit entitlement is also likely to be affected by his becoming a higher-rate taxpayer. Last but not least, he will have a hefty additional tax charge on the use of his company car as a ‘benefit in kind’ to reckon with.
Then there is the question of moving – as we all know, moving house is an expensive and traumatic process even if you move between areas with comparable house prices, and the relocation package he’s been offered isn’t that generous. Edward would unfortunately be faced with a move from North to South, where house prices for 3- and 4-bedroomed homes are ca 2-3 times as high, and would also need to take on a much higher mortgage to buy a comparable property or be faced with the prospect of downgrading to a much smaller one. This is equally daunting at a time when mortgage interest rates are already shooting up from their historic and artificially-engineered lows. Quite apart from the deleterious effect on his finances and or living accommodation, the move would leave him less quality time with his young family, and arguably a lower 'quality of life'.
A 'no-brainer', you might say, and unfortunately you’d be right…
Edward also faces another, and arguably more pernicious, dilemma - by not taking the promotion, he will also mark himself out as someone who ‘lacks incentive’, and is therefore unlikely to progress any further, and as a result he may even end up being a prime target for any compulsory redundancies in the future. Unfortunately, middle managers are particularly vulnerable as targets for corporate 'economies' resulting from the NI hike at present, so this is not an issue he can safely ignore.
Mary will also lose the opportunity to take on more work, which might otherwise have been possible if Edward's salary had increased enough to fund childcare, thereby depriving the economy of another valuable and much-needed worker.
Last, but not least, there is an important financial consequence for the treasury itself. By not taking up the new position, Edward will deprive HMRC of a significant amount of additional tax revenue every year. If the 40% tax threshold had been raised to £80,000 (as promised by our last prime minister but two during his 2019 leadership campaign), Edward might well have come to a different conclusion and taken the new job. His additional salary, even when taxed at only 20%, would then have raised an extra £4000 p.a. HMRC will also miss out on any tax which Mary might have paid on her increased earnings, had she and Edward been able to afford childcare and enable her to return to full time work........
This example is not untypical of the dilemma many UK middle-earners
are facing. Apart from the blow to their own self-esteem that their inability
to progress their careers delivers, and the likely consequent effect on their individual job
satisfaction and productiveness, this type of problem stifles growth in the
economy as a whole. As the example shows, it also has the potential to decrease significantly the overall net tax-take,thereby reducing the Treasury's ability to fund important infrastructure and other projects. Last but not least, the personal frustration involved may lead Edward and Mary to reconsider their 'verdicts' on the competence of the current government when it comes to polling day...what price the plaintive refrain "..what about the workers ?.." first heard in the 1970s and now trumpeted regularly by our current PM ?
However, there is a serious flaw in this argument - £50k nowadays is certainly not the 'princely' salary it once was, given excessive house prices and the soaring cost of living, particularly for single-earner families. More importantly, it is workers and small business entrepreneurs in the private sector such as Edward who are best-placed to lift us out of our current economic trough through their own enterprise. Neither Government, nor indeed the public sector as a whole, can do this effectively without their help, since they don't actually generate any 'real' wealth.
Further up the age scale, older workers in their 50s and early 60s in particular, when faced with similar disincentives, and the continuing 'last bastion of discriminatory practices' that is age discrimination, will be tempted to leave the job market altogether earlier than they might otherwise. This will be especially attractive to them if they have already managed to accumulate sufficient pension income and savings to get by in retirement, their children have all ‘flown the nest’ and their mortgages have been largely repaid. The recent, and much needed sharp uplift in interest rates (now sadly on the decline again) will also serve to boost their unearned income from any savings they might have managed to accumulate.
We know that this 'flight from the workplace' has already started to happen, with reports suggesting that upwards of a million workers have gone AWOL from the job market since the start of the pandemic, many of whom will now never return. This is often blamed on the Covid 'event', but is more likely to be driven by a marked lack of incentive to work. The exodus is likely to contiue in 2025-6, given the dramatic effect a bank rate rise from 0.1% to the 4.0% over less than a year had on savings income (despite the fact that the banks were so laggardly in raising their rates to savers in line with bank rate hikes), and industry cutbacks due to the employer NI increases.
The skills and expertise of these early retirees, accumulated over a working lifetime, are desperately needed just now to help us 'work smarter' and enhance our productivity. In a recent blog I’ve put forward specific arguments as to why we should entice some of these early leavers and the over 65s back into the job market....and how we might do it.
In short, we need a radical re-think on tax policy in order
to release the stranglehold on growth and enterprise that ill-conceived historic and existing policies have engineered. This is despite the mess the Treasury has got itself into over the years by stoking up national debt and the resulting servicing burden. Increasing wealth generation is our only hope for the economic future, and high taxes always place a drag on this.
We should remember, however, that many of our older pensioners are simply too frail and infirm to return to work. They will need society's help to get through the cost of living crisis and its aftermath, and we should not simply abandon them to their fate.
There are all too many reports of pensioners terrified of the consequences of the progressive increases in energy costs, who are still fully expecting to go through this coming winter and next without being able to heat their homes, and / or eat properly. This is despite the forced reinstatement of the Winter Fuel allowance for some. Many pensioners with at least some savings they have put by to provide care in their old age have been hit particularly hard over the past few years by punishingly low interest rates, and have seen the value of their increasingly meagre savings income and pensions eroded by increased costs. They should at least now be able to take some comfort from the rises in interest rates.There is a glimmer of light on fuel costs for some in the 'promise' by OFGEM to insist electricity and gas suppliers offer at least one no-standing charge tariff by 1.1.26, which would remove the current universal penalty on low users imposed by historically sky-high standing charges. We will see whether this actually materialises and a cap is placed on the unit rates offered.
We urgently need to provide additional help for pensioners, many of whom have little or no savings and are dependent on the State pension and whatever occupational pension pots they may have accrued during their working lifetimes. Those who retired after 2010 and took out annuities will have suffered from particularly poor annuity returns (due to the excessively low gilt yields caused by central banks' quantitative easing policies) which they will remain locked into. An uplift in their incomes could easily be achieved by a simple modification of the tax system.
Currently, although the basic state pension is not taxed 'at source', it is taken into account by HMRC in assessing tax liability. For anyone lucky enough to have additional earnings from an occupational pension and/or savings which exceed the personal tax threshold (currently frozen until at least 2028 at a meagre £12.5k for a single person), part or all of their State pension income will taxed at 20% or more. This makes no sense, given that they have already 'bought' their state pension 'pot' from HMG through their lifetime compulsory NI contributions, and are now being asked to pay for it again through tax on the income it generates. The State Pension should be theirs by right in its entirety, and not 'raided' in this way by HMRC. We should therefore exempt the state pension from the tax assessment process altogether. Any additional income through occupational pensions should only be taxed at a flat rate of 20%, and excluded from total income calculations.
Let's now look at the other side of the debate regarding taxation. The argument currently put forward for not reducing the tax burden is that lowering taxes will involve excessive additional borrowing, and we need to pay down our debt before we embark on any tax cuts.
This unfortunately was always a shortsighted and potentially very damaging approach (but sadly endorsed by the Markets in 2022 (largely due to the unbelievably incompetent way in which the costings were ignored). The key assumption that the current policy makes is that maintaining or even increasing tax levels will enable us to bring inflation under control and pay off some of our accumulated national debt relatively quickly, and we should wait until we've done this before lowering the tax burden.
This assumption is fundamentally flawed – the size of the debt mountain (currently running well into the £trillions) is now so large that worldwide cost increases and the resulting rapid interest rate rises alone will ensure both personal and Government debt continues to increase whatever we do in the short term. It is only by increasing our national productivity and engineering consistent medium- and long-term growth that we stand any chance of escaping the ‘debt vortex’ that we’re currently stuck in. The recent 'stagflation' of the economy and and gloomy announcements from the BoE and the IMF of poor economic prospects to come for UK only serves to confirm the existing strategy has failed, and emphasise the need for a significant policy change.
If we don’t take action to escape this pervasive economic trap, we will leave our kids the
very debt legacy that proponents of ‘tax and spend’ from both ends of the
political spectrum claim will be avoided.
As we have seen, the Markets have effectively 'put the frighteners on' any excessive and uncosted borrowing. Their caution, though understandable, doesn't alter our need to escape the debt vortex. I have suggested an alternative approach in a recent blog, focusing on enhancing our productivity, which we might take pending an improvement in the world economy.
Let's hope this improvement in world fortunes comes sooner rather and later, and the chancellor doesn't manage to introduce yet another increase the tax burden again in the forthcoming budget. With Reeves seemingly still stuck in Austerity 2.0 mode, though, I don't hold out much hope of much financial 'good cheer', in the short term at least.
Viv
Version Date 4.2.23; Revised 5.8.25
Comments
Post a Comment